Milk Madness
by Chris Edwards, Director of Tax Policy Studies, Cato Institute
The federal government has subsidized and regulated
the dairy industry since the 1930s. A system of “marketing
order” regulations was enacted in 1937. A dairy price
support program was added in 1949. An income support
program for dairy farmers was added in 2002.
As part of this year’s farm bill, Congress may
reauthorize dairy programs, but they are among the most
illogical of all farm programs.
1
The government spends
billions of dollars reducing food costs through programs
such as food stamps, yet dairy programs increase milk
prices. Dairy programs create milk cartels, yet federal law
generally prohibits cartels. Current dairy policies don’t
make any sense, and they are ripe for repeal in 2007.
Structure of Federal Dairy Programs
Marketing Orders. The Federal Milk Marketing Order
system sets minimum prices for milk products. About twothirds of milk is produced under federal marketing orders
in 10 regions of the country. Most of the rest is produced
under California’s separate system of regulations.
The federal system is structured around four classes of
milk product: fluid milk, ice cream and yogurt, cheese, and
butter and dry milk. Each month the U.S. Department of
Agriculture sets separate prices for fluid milk in the 10
regions, and nationwide prices for the other three types of
dairy product, using various formulae. Processors must
pay for milk on the basis of how it will be used, but all
farmers in a region receive the same blended price.
Marketing orders essentially create cartels that limit
competition. Entrepreneurs are not allowed to supply milk
at less than the government prices. The system also limits
the ability of milk producers from lower-cost regions, such
as the Midwest, from gaining market share in higher-cost
regions, such as the Southeast.
Price Support Program. The Milk Price Support
Program keeps market prices artificially high by
guaranteeing that the government will purchase any
amount of cheese, butter, and nonfat dry milk from
processors at a set minimum price. Those guaranteed
purchases of storable products create steady demand and
higher prices for the products of all dairy farmers. Note
that the price support program props up dairy prices at the
same time that the income support program encourages
overproduction, which puts downward pressure on prices.
Income Support Program. The Milk Income Loss
Contract program, which was enacted in 2002, provides
cash subsidies to milk producers when market prices fall
below target levels. The 1996 farm law was supposed to
reduce dairy subsidies, but instead dairy subsidies
increased as a result of a series of supplemental spending
bills in the late 1990s. Those supplemental “market loss”
subsidies ultimately morphed into the more permanent
MILC program in 2002.
Import Barriers. U.S. imports of milk, butter, cheese,
and other dairy products are limited by “tariff rate quotas,”
which are tariffs that vary by import volume. Import
barriers are a complement to dairy price supports because
they help keep domestic prices artificially high. Without
import barriers, U.S. consumers could simply purchase
lower-priced foreign dairy products. Imports of cheese,
butter, and dried milk are limited to about five percent or
less of U.S. consumption.
2
Export Subsidies. The Dairy Export Incentive
Program was introduced in 1985 to provide cash subsidies
to U.S. dairy producers who sell in foreign markets.
Because U.S. dairy policies keep domestic prices above
world prices, producers would otherwise have little interest
in selling abroad. Thus, dairy export subsidies create an
incentive to export and help remove surpluses caused by
overproduction from the domestic market.
Effects of Federal Dairy Programs
The USDA says that the purpose of milk marketing
orders is to “promote orderly milk marketing relationships
to ensure adequate supplies of milk and dairy products to
meet consumers’ demands at reasonable prices.”
3
But it
unlikely that dairy products need subsidies and controls to
fulfill those goals. After all, the market price system achieves “adequate supplies” at “reasonable prices”
without government help for thousands of other products
such as automobiles, books, and computers.
In fact, current dairy policies do not deliver
“reasonable” prices at all. Because of federal controls,
milk prices are higher than they would otherwise be, which
penalizes millions of families. The Organization for
Economic Cooperation and Development found that U.S.
dairy policies create a 26 percent “implicit tax” on milk
consumers.
4
This milk “tax” is regressive, causing
relatively greater harm to low-income families.
The Government Accountability Office compared U.S.
dairy prices to world prices over a seven-year period.
5
It
found that U.S. prices for butter averaged twice the world
price, cheese prices were about 50 percent higher, and
nonfat dry milk prices were about 30 percent higher.
The taxpayer costs of dairy policies are also of
concern. Those costs range from zero to $2.5 billion
annually depending on market conditions.
6
Dairy policies
are expected to cost taxpayers at least $600 million over
the next decade.
7
U.S. dairy policies also harm international trade
relations. Dairy subsidies are a barrier to moving ahead
with the stalled Doha Round of trade talks. U.S. trade
protections for agriculture have inhibited the liberalization
of trade in other sectors, to the detriment of U.S.
companies that want to expand their exports and
consumers who would benefit from lower prices.
Entrepreneurs Not Allowed
The irrationality of federal dairy controls was driven
home by the struggle over dairy entrepreneur Hein
Hettinga in 2006.
8
Hettinga, a Dutch immigrant, began a
dairy farm and milk bottling plant in Arizona in the 1990s
outside of the government system. He sold his milk to
local Arizona stores and to Costco in California at 20 cents
per gallon less than government-regulated milk. His low
prices met with a strong demand, and his business
expanded rapidly. Costco executives believed that
consumers were being “gouged” by the government
system, and they were happy to provide customers with
Hettinga’s discount milk.
However, farmers and others in the regulated system
were not happy with the competition from Hettinga. They
pushed for Congress to intervene, and a political battle
ensued, which cost more than $5 million in lobbying fees.
Both Democrats and Republicans sought to protect homestate dairy interests, and they teamed up to crush Hettinga
and close the channel through which he was operating.
9
Based on his experience, Hettinga said “I had an
awakening . . . it’s not totally free enterprise in the United
States.”
10
That lack of free enterprise not only keeps milk
prices high, but results in a U.S. dairy industry that is not
as innovative as the less regulated New Zealand industry.
11
The dependence on government purchases of dry milk, for
example, has “removed the incentive for companies to
diversify and invest in the production of high-value dairy
products of the future.”
12
Conclusions
U.S. dairy programs are Byzantine in their complexity
and create the most rigidly controlled of all agricultural
markets. The ultimate effects are to transfer income from
consumers and taxpayers to dairy businesses and to stifle
innovation in this $90 billion industry.
In this year’s farm bill, the Democrats have a chance
to repeal the special interest giveaways of prior Republican
farm bills, including the regressive “milk tax.”
1
For background on this year’s farm legislation, see
http://www.cato.org/downsizing/agriculture. Also see Sallie James,
“Milking the Customers: The High Cost of U.S. Dairy Policies,”
Cato Institute, November 9, 2006.
2
Daniel Sumner and Joseph Balagtas, “United States’
Agricultural Systems: An Overview of U.S. Dairy Policy,” 2002,
p. 8,
http://aic.ucdavis.edu/oa/working.html. 3
James Miller and Don Blayney, “Dairy Backgrounder,” United
States Department of Agriculture, July 2006,
http://www.ers.usda.gov/publications/ldp/2006/07jul/ldpm14501.
4
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development,
“Agricultural Policies in OECD Countries: Monitoring and
Evaluation,” 2005, p. 294.
5
Government Accountability Office, “Dairy Industry:
Information on Milk Prices, Factors Affecting Prices, and Dairy
Policy Options,” GAO-05-50, December 29, 2004, p. 106.
6
Ralph Chite, “Dairy Policy Issues,” Congressional Research
Service, June 16, 2006, p. 7.
7
U.S. Department of Agriculture, “Administration’s Farm Bill
Proposal,” undated,
http://www.usda.gov/documents/07sumbudgetscore.pdf.
8
Dan Morgan, Sarah Cohen, and Gilbert Gaul, “Dairy Industry
Crushed Innovator Who Bested Price-Control System,”
Washington Post, December 10, 2006, p. A1.
9
Public Law 109-215 was enacted in April 2006. For further
information see Chite and
http://www.keepmilkpriceslow.org.
10
Morgan, Cohen, and Gaul.
11
Joseph Balagtas, “U.S. Dairy Policy: Analysis and Options,”
American Enterprise Institute, May 17, 2007, p. 9,
http://www.aei.org/research/farmbill.
12
International Dairy Foods Association, “Ensuring a Healthy
U.S. Dairy Industry,” 2007,
http://www.healthydairyindustry.org.